How Asian economies can avoid asset bubbles

0 CommentsPrint E-mail China Daily, December 24, 2009
Adjust font size:

Just as Asian economies started to recover from the global recession, policymakers and markets began worrying over unwarranted asset price increases. While the worries are global, especially in the case of stock markets, the risks of asset price bubbles seem particularly high in Asia, where abundant liquidity is driving up prices of all sorts of assets from real estate in the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region (SAR) and Singapore to Chinese art.

Where is the liquidity coming from? Capital inflows have received a lot of attention lately. Financial capital is flowing into Asia, attracted by the continent's relatively good economic prospects. More important, for most economies, is a dramatic easing of domestic monetary conditions since late last year that has fueled domestic liquidity.

In part, the easing of monetary conditions in Asia was deliberate, a policy response to sharp weaker growth. But some of the easing of monetary conditions was not deliberate. Economies with an exchange rate somewhat or completely fixed to the US dollar and fairly open capital markets are "importing" the loose US monetary policy. In some economies, those imported monetary conditions sit oddly with domestic economic conditions. In many Asian economies, spare capacity is much smaller than in the US and cyclical unemployment much lower.

Against this backdrop, prominent policymakers in Asia have warned of the threats posed to financial stability by the US monetary policy. I would not put it that way. The US monetary policy stance seems about right, given the depressed state of the US economy, with unemployment at around 10 percent. Moreover, there is no credit growth in the US at the moment. The main problem for Asia is the importation of US monetary conditions under fixed or managed exchange rate regimes to economies in very different economic circumstances. But the worries expressed by these policymakers underscore the tensions that this state of affairs generates at the moment.

What should governments do to mitigate these risks? Governments in several Asian economies have tightened prudential regulation and used other administrative measures. They have increased loan-loss coverage ratios and minimum down payments for mortgages and restricted lending to property developers. The Chinese mainland has taken steps to try to avoid new lending going to the stock market and to increase the supply of stocks by allowing IPOs again. Taiwan has banned foreign investors from putting money into the island's fixed-term deposits. But, except for Australia, other economies in the region have so far refrained from tightening their overall monetary policy.

Looking ahead, more prudential and other administrative measures can be taken, such as increasing loan-loss and minimum down payment ratios and higher reserve requirements. Administrative measures may not be enough, though. Adjustments to monetary and exchange rate policy may be needed. To decide what to do in this area, in my view policymakers should first determine what the main problem is: capital inflows or (too) rapid domestic liquidity creation. And, if too rapid domestic liquidity creation is the main problem, to what extent is this because of loose monetary conditions imported via the exchange rate regime?

If capital inflows are a big problem, compared to domestic liquidity creation, economies cannot rely too much on higher interest rates to dampen financial risks, because the increase in capital inflows owing to higher interest rates may outweigh the impact on domestic liquidity. This may especially be the case in some of the smaller, financially more open economies in Asia. If the openness of their capital market creates such big constraints, they should consider measures to control or discourage capital inflows. They can also absorb some of the pressure by allowing their currencies to strengthen. East Asian economies tend to worry about loosing their competitiveness if they let their currencies strengthen unilaterally. With so many economies facing the same problem, it would make sense to strive for more cooperation on exchange rate management, formally and informally.

If capital inflows are not a major problem but the cyclical differences vis-a-vis the US mean that loose monetary policy is very inappropriate for domestic economic conditions, there may be room to tighten monetary policy, including raising interest rate.

In my view, this is the situation on the mainland, where the role of capital inflows compared to domestic liquidity creation is smaller than many think. Policymakers have at times been unnecessarily reluctant to raise interest rates. In the first half of 2009, net financial capital inflows were equivalent to only 3.3 percent of domestic credit creation. Given the mainland's capital controls and the relatively small role of capital inflows, the pros of higher interest rates seem to outweigh the cons. This may be the case in other Asian economies as well, particularly if such moves are accompanied by tightening capital controls further.

Some are reluctant to tighten the monetary policy because of low inflation, the traditional trigger for monetary policy action. But the global financial crisis has shown the dangers of neglecting asset price increases in monetary and financial policymaking. In key high-income economies traditionally geared only toward inflation, the monetary policy was loose for too long, even as asset prices rose to levels deemed worrisome by many. In all cases, introducing more exchange rate flexibility would help discourage inflows. By introducing a useful two-way risk on the foreign exchange market, a more flexible exchange rate gives monetary policy more independence to be in line with domestic needs.

In addition, opportunistic timing of structural reforms can reduce risks on asset prices and quality. The supply of financial titles can be increased, by deepening the financial sector, including in the bond and equity markets. In places where interest rates on bank deposits are still capped, easing the caps and stimulating the development of more long term saving instruments would help absorb financial surpluses. Finally, opportunistically introducing or increasing capital gains taxes on equity and real estate would reduce pressures as well.

As Asian growth prospects are likely to continue to differ significantly from those in the US in the coming years, this may well be a good time to take the steps needed to make monetary policy more independent, so that the monetary stance can be more in line with domestic economic conditions.

Print E-mail Bookmark and Share

Comments

No comments.

Add your comments...

  • User Name Required
  • Your Comment
  • Comments are moderated and generally will be posted if they are on-topic and not abusive.
Send your storiesGet more from China.org.cnMobileRSSNewsletter
主站蜘蛛池模板: 国产欧美色一区二区三区| 好男人官网在线观看免费播放| 亚洲性久久久影院| 男人边吃奶边做视频免费网站 | 欧美亚洲校园第一页| 亚洲精品乱码久久久久久蜜桃 | 国产精品女在线观看| aaaa级少妇高潮大片在线观看| 性高朝久久久久久久| 久久99精品国产99久久6| 日韩欧美亚洲综合久久| 亚洲人成在线播放| 欧美成在线观看| 亚洲精品一二区| 男生和女生一起差差差很痛的视频| 另类视频第一页| 老色鬼久久综合第一| 国产中文制服丝袜另类| 高h视频在线观看| 国产成人精品综合久久久| 亚洲丝袜第一页| 国产精品亚洲欧美大片在线看| 91av最新地址| 国内一级黄色片| 99久久精品免费看国产一区二区三区| 女女同恋のレズビアン漫画| 一本色道久久88精品综合| 成人午夜性视频欧美成人| 中文字幕人成乱码熟女| 无码一区二区三区在线观看| 国产乱人伦无无码视频试看| 97久久天天综合色天天综合色 | 最近中文字幕视频高清| 亚洲中文字幕无码久久| 欧美人与动zoz0大全| 亚洲午夜精品在线| 欧美性v视频播放| 亚洲国产成AV人天堂无码| 欧美日在线观看| 亚洲国产日韩欧美综合久久| 欧美又大粗又爽又黄大片视频|