Cities need 'low-end' workers to prosper

By Liu Ming
0 Comment(s)Print E-mail China Daily, August 18, 2016
Adjust font size:

Wang Xiaoying / China Daily

Some people suppose industrial upgrading means waning demand for "low-end" workforce, and therefore urban areas should restrict the inflow of "low-end" workers by implementing a stricter household registration policy. This is a big misunderstanding.

It is not true that big cities with high labor productivity and high-income levels require few low-skilled workers. In fact, the concentration of high-skilled talents in one place increases the demand for low-skilled workers. The proportion of blue-collar workers should generally be higher in bigger cities compared with smaller ones.

High-skilled talents and low-skilled workers are complementary to each other. In a society with high division of labor, low-skilled workers can benefit from highly skilled talents and improve their lot. For instance, workers in the service industry who get more chances to serve foreigners can learn a foreign language faster than other workers. And the more people earn, the more they spend to get services, which in turn requires more low-skilled workers to serve them.

Research shows that in the United States, one post in a high-tech industry can create five posts in other industries-two in the comparatively high-end service industry (such as the medical and legal professions) and three in the consumption-centric service industry (such as retail and restaurants).

But unlike major US cities, their Chinese counterparts have failed to increase the employment of low-skilled workers. In major US cities, the proportions of high-skilled talents and low-skilled workers are both high, but that of middle-skilled workers is lower compared with smaller cities and towns.

The problem with middle-skilled workers is that despite being unable to compete with high-skilled talents, they are reluctant to do low-skilled work. That's why they are less likely to make big US cities their base.

Statistics show that China's big cities attract more high-skilled talents-but fewer low-skilled workers-than middle- and small-sized cities. This is not because China's big cities don't need low-skilled workers, but because they implement strict policies to restrict the inflow of such workers. Restricting the inflow of low-skilled workers in big cities, however, could have a negative impact on urban development.

When enterprises in big cities have difficulty in hiring low-skilled workers to render low-end services, they have to hire comparatively high-skilled people to do the jobs. That's the reason why some college students do menial work that could be accomplished by people with a high school diploma, and this is a waste of talent.

Since there are not enough low-skilled workers in the service industry to serve the high-skilled talents in big cities-and demand exceeds supply-there has been a rapid growth of salary in the service industry. And the high costs have forced many enterprises to keep the recruitment of low-skilled workers to the barest minimum.

As a result, high-skilled talents spend more time on service-oriented work instead of improving their productivity. And the decline of productivity of high-skilled talents undermines the competitiveness of an entire city.

Moreover, restricting the inflow of low-skilled workers in major cities also reduces migrant workers' consumption. Migrant workers save more money for future risks because they cannot be covered by the urban social security system. They don't spend money on durables, for they believe they will eventually have to return to their hometowns.

Restricting workers' mobility in urban areas also seriously distorts the demand and supply of labor, undermining economic growth and competitiveness of cities, as well as the well-being of urban residents.

So instead of restricting the inflow of migrant workers, city authorities should try to cope with the social problems related to labor mobility by enhancing infrastructure construction and public services, and improving their urban management.

The author is a professor at Antai College of Economics and Management in Shanghai Jiao Tong University.

Follow China.org.cn on Twitter and Facebook to join the conversation.
Print E-mail Bookmark and Share

Go to Forum >>0 Comment(s)

No comments.

Add your comments...

  • User Name Required
  • Your Comment
  • Enter the words you see:   
    Racist, abusive and off-topic comments may be removed by the moderator.
Send your storiesGet more from China.org.cnMobileRSSNewsletter
主站蜘蛛池模板: 色av.com| 美女被免费网站91色| 无套日出白浆在线播放| 亚洲av成人精品网站在线播放| 浮力影院第一页小视频国产在线观看免费 | 国产精品自在线| av网站免费线看| 婷婷丁香五月中文字幕| 中文字幕亚洲日本岛国片| 日本影片和韩国影片网站推荐| 亚洲AV无码乱码麻豆精品国产| 欧美成人免费网站| 亚洲精品午夜国产va久久成人| 男国少年梦电影| 免费看美女隐私全部| 精品香蕉一区二区三区| 国产99在线a视频| 色橹橹欧美在线观看视频高清 | 国产91免费在线观看| 国产精品va在线播放| 4hu四虎永久免在线视| 在线一区二区三区| 99热免费在线观看| 天天av天天翘天天综合网| re99热久久这里只有精品| 小娇乳H边走边欢1V1视频国产| 上原瑞穗最全番号| 成品网站nike源码1688免费| 丰满少妇被猛烈进入无码| 日产精品久久久久久久| 久久久久免费精品国产| 日本天堂视频在线观看| 久久只有这才是精品99| 日韩aa在线观看| 久久国产加勒比精品无码| 日韩一级片在线观看| 久久国产精品女| 日本亚洲国产一区二区三区| 久久久久99精品成人片直播| 无码一区二区三区AV免费| 中文字幕第二十页|