Uncertain link between financial regulators, outcomes

By Howard Davies
0 Comment(s)Print E-mail Shanghai Daily, March 13, 2013
Adjust font size:

In?the early phases of the financial crisis, it was fashionable to argue that the United States' system of regulation needed a fundamental structural overhaul.

Differences of opinion between the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) had obstructed effective oversight of investment banks and derivatives trading (only the US believes that it makes sense to regulate securities and derivatives separately).

Indeed, the plethora of separate banking regulators had created opportunities for banks to arbitrage the system in search of a more indulgent approach to capital.

Likewise, the lack of a federal insurance regulator had left AIG regulated by the Office of Thrift Supervision (OTS) and the New York State Insurance Department, which proved to be a wholly inadequate arrangement.

Little has come of these arguments. The Dodd-Frank Act did succeed in putting the OTS out of its misery, but jealous congressional oversight committees have prevented a merger of the SEC and CFTC, and nothing has been done to rationalize banking supervision. So the American system looks remarkably similar to the one that turned a collective blind eye to the rise of fatal tensions in the early 2000s.

One factor that contributed to institutional stasis was the absence of a persuasive alternative.

In the decade or so leading up to the meltdown of 2007-2008, the global trend was toward regulatory integration. Almost 40 countries had introduced single regulators.

The movement began in Scandinavia in the early 1990s, but the most dramatic change came in 1997, when the United Kingdom introduced its Financial Services Authority (I was its first chairman).

One-stop shop

There were economies of scale and scope, and financial firms typically like the idea of a one-stop (or, at worst, a two-stop) shop.

A single regulator might be expected to develop a more coherent view of trends in the financial sector as a whole.

Unfortunately, these benefits did not materialize, or at least not everywhere. It is hard to argue that the British system performed any more effectively than the American, so the single-regulator movement has suffered reputational damage.

The truth is that it is hard to identify any correlation between regulatory structure and success in heading off or responding to the financial crisis. Among the single-regulator countries, Singapore and the Scandinavians were successful in dodging most of the fatal bullets, while the UK evidently was not.

Does it matter whether the central bank is directly involved?

Many central bankers maintain that the central bank is uniquely placed to deal with systemic risks, and that it is essential to carry out monetary and financial policies in the same institution. Again, it is hard to find strong empirical support for that argument.

The Dutch and American central banks, with direct oversight of their banking systems, were no more effective in identifying potentially dangerous systemic issues than were non-central bank regulators elsewhere. Canada is often cited as a country that steered its banks away from trouble, even though they sit uncomfortably close to US markets. But the Bank of Canada is not now, and has never been, a hands-on institutional supervisor.

So perhaps the US Congress has been right to conclude that changing the structure of regulatory bodies is less important than getting the content of regulation right.

It is difficult now to discern a coherent pattern. Certainly, the trend toward full-service single regulators outside the central bank has slowed to a crawl (though Indonesia is consolidating regulators at present).

There is no consensus on the role of the central bank: in around a third of countries, it is the dominant player, in another third it has responsibilities for banks only, while in the remaining third it is a system overseer only. We could see this as a controlled experiment to try to identify a preferred model.

After all, financial systems are not so different from one another. But there is no sign of a considered assessment being prepared, which might at least help countries to make better-informed choices, even if it did not conclude that one model was unambiguously best.

Howard Davies, former chairman of Britain's Financial Services Authority, deputy governor of the Bank of England, and director of the London School of Economics, is a professor at Sciences Po in Paris. Shanghai Daily condensed the article.

 

Print E-mail Bookmark and Share

Go to Forum >>0 Comment(s)

No comments.

Add your comments...

  • User Name Required
  • Your Comment
  • Enter the words you see:   
    Racist, abusive and off-topic comments may be removed by the moderator.
Send your storiesGet more from China.org.cnMobileRSSNewsletter
主站蜘蛛池模板: 无人高清视频完整版在线观看| 色久综合网精品一区二区| 日本全黄三级在线观看| 免费看美女被靠到爽的视频| 欧美亚洲另类视频| 巨大黑人极品videos中国| 亚洲午夜久久久精品电影院| 丰满大白屁股ass| 波多野结衣中文无毒不卡| 国产成人tv在线观看| eeuss影院www在线观看免费| 日韩欧美卡一卡二卡新区| 伊人久久大香线蕉avapp下载| 黄瓜视频在线播放| 大又大又粗又硬又爽少妇毛片| 久久成人免费电影| 狠狠色婷婷久久一区二区三区| 国产免费看插插插视频| 99久久精品费精品国产| 日本污视频网站| 亚洲精品国产成人| 色哟哟精品视频在线观看| 国产精品女同一区二区| 一区二区三区免费看| 日韩视频免费看| 亚洲综合视频在线| 老师您的兔子好软水好多动漫视频| 国产精品国产三级国产AV′| 一区二区三区影院| 日韩欧美不卡视频| 亚洲精品免费视频| 老色鬼欧美精品| 国产激情电影综合在线看| chinese乱子伦xxxx视频播放| 日本娇小videos精品| 亚洲成AV人片在线播放无码| 国产丝袜第一页| 天天操天天干天搞天天射| 久久久久久夜精品精品免费啦| 欧美日韩国产专区| 内射一区二区精品视频在线观看|